Analyzing Two-Mode Networks
Two-Mode Networks
This handout deals with the network analysis of two-mode networks. Note that in the literature there is some terminological slippage. Two-mode networks are a type of social network. By definition two-mode networks can be represented using rectangular adjacency matrices (sometimes called affiliation matrices in sociology).
In this case, two-mode networks fall under the general category of “two-mode data.” Any data set that has information on two types of objects (e.g., people and variables) is two-mode data so two-mode networks are just a special case of two-mode data.
In this sense, a useful distinction, due to Borgatti & Everett, is useful. This is that between the “modes” and the “ways” of a data matrix. So most data matrices are two-ways, in that they have at least two dimensions (e.g., the row and column dimensions).
But some data matrices (like the usual adjacency matrix in regular network data) only collect information on a single type of entity, so they are “one mode, two ways.” But sometimes we have network data on two sets of objects, in which case, we use a data matrix that has “two-modes” (sets of nodes) and “two ways” (rows and columns).
So what makes a network a “two-mode network”? Well, a two-mode network is different from a regular network, because it has two sets of nodes not just one. So instead of \(V\) now we have \(V_1\) and \(V_2\). Moreover, the edges in a two-mode network only go from nodes in one set to nodes in the other set; there are no within-node-set edges.
Bipartite Graphs
This restriction makes the graph that represents a two-mode network a special kind of graph called a bipartite graph. A graph is bipartite if the set of nodes in the graph can be divided into two groups, such that relations go from nodes in one set to nodes in the other set.
Note that bipartite graphs can be be used to represent both two-mode and regular one mode networks, as long as the above condition holds. For instance, a dating network with 100% heterosexual people in it will yield a bipartite graph based on the dating relation, with men in one set and women on the other node set, even though it’s a one-mode network.
So whether or not a graph is bipartite is something you can check for.
Let’s see how that works. Let us load the most famous two-mode network data set (kind of the Drosophila of two-mode network analysis; one of the most repeatedly analyzed social structures in history: For a classic sampling of such analyses see here) a network composed of eighteen women from the social elite of a tiny town in the south in the 1930s who attended fourteen social events (Breiger 1974):
Now we already know this is a bipartite graph. However, let’s say you are new and you’ve never heard of these data. You can check whether the graph you loaded up is bipartite or not by using the igraph
function is_bipartite
:
Which returns TRUE
as an answer. Had we loaded up any old non-bipartite graph, the answer would have been:
Which makes sense because that’s just a regular old graph.
Note that if we check the bipartite graph object, it looks like any other igraph
object:
IGRAPH 1074643 UN-B 32 89 --
+ attr: type (v/l), name (v/c)
+ edges from 1074643 (vertex names):
[1] EVELYN --6/27 EVELYN --3/2 EVELYN --4/12 EVELYN --9/26
[5] EVELYN --2/25 EVELYN --5/19 EVELYN --9/16 EVELYN --4/8
[9] LAURA --6/27 LAURA --3/2 LAURA --4/12 LAURA --2/25
[13] LAURA --5/19 LAURA --3/15 LAURA --9/16 THERESA --3/2
[17] THERESA --4/12 THERESA --9/26 THERESA --2/25 THERESA --5/19
[21] THERESA --3/15 THERESA --9/16 THERESA --4/8 BRENDA --6/27
[25] BRENDA --4/12 BRENDA --9/26 BRENDA --2/25 BRENDA --5/19
[29] BRENDA --3/15 BRENDA --9/16 CHARLOTTE--4/12 CHARLOTTE--9/26
+ ... omitted several edges
But we can tell that the graph is a two-mode network because we have links starting with people with old lady names from the 1930s (which are also the names of a bunch of kids in middle school in 2024) and ending with events that have dates in them. So the (undirected) edge is \(person-event\).
The graph is undirected because the “membership” or “attendance” relation between a person and an organization/event doesn’t have a natural directionality.
Another way of checking the “bipartiteness” of a graph in igraph
is by using the bipartite_mapping
function.
Let’s see what it does:
$res
[1] TRUE
$type
EVELYN LAURA THERESA BRENDA CHARLOTTE FRANCES ELEANOR PEARL
FALSE FALSE FALSE FALSE FALSE FALSE FALSE FALSE
RUTH VERNE MYRNA KATHERINE SYLVIA NORA HELEN DOROTHY
FALSE FALSE FALSE FALSE FALSE FALSE FALSE FALSE
OLIVIA FLORA 6/27 3/2 4/12 9/26 2/25 5/19
FALSE FALSE TRUE TRUE TRUE TRUE TRUE TRUE
3/15 9/16 4/8 6/10 2/23 4/7 11/21 8/3
TRUE TRUE TRUE TRUE TRUE TRUE TRUE TRUE
This function takes the candidate bipartite graph as input and returns to objects: res
is just a check to see if the graph is actually bipartite (TRUE
in this case), type
is a logical vector of dimensions \(M + N\) (where \(M\) is the number of nodes in the person set and \(N\) is the number of nodes in the event set) dividing the nodes into two groups. Here people get FALSE
and events get TRUE
, but this designations are arbitrary (a kind of dummy coding; FALSE
= 0 and TRUE
= 1).
We can add this as a node attribute to our graph so that way we know which node is in which set:
The Bi-Adjacency (Affiliation) Matrix
Once you have your bipartite graph loaded up, you may want (if the graph is small enough) to check out the graph’s affiliation matrix \(A\).
This works just like before, except that now we use the as_biadjacency_matrix
function:
6/27 3/2 4/12 9/26 2/25 5/19 3/15 9/16 4/8 6/10 2/23 4/7 11/21 8/3
EVELYN 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 0
LAURA 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0
THERESA 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0
BRENDA 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0
CHARLOTTE 0 0 1 1 1 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
FRANCES 0 0 1 0 1 1 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0
ELEANOR 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0
PEARL 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 0
RUTH 0 0 0 0 1 0 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0
VERNE 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 0 0 1 0 0
MYRNA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 0 1 0 0
KATHERINE 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 0 1 1 1
SYLVIA 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1
NORA 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1
HELEN 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 1 1 1 0 0
DOROTHY 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 0
OLIVIA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 1 0 0 0
FLORA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 1 0 0 0
In this matrix we list one set of nodes in the rows and the other set is in the columns. Each cell \(a_{ij} = 1\) if row node \(i\) is affiliated with column node \(j\), otherwise \(a_{ij} = 0\).
The Bipartite Adjacency Matrix
Note that if we were to use the regular as_adjacency_matrix
function on a bipartite graph, we get a curious version of the adjacency matrix:
EVELYN LAURA THERESA BRENDA CHARLOTTE FRANCES ELEANOR PEARL RUTH
EVELYN 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
LAURA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
THERESA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
BRENDA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
CHARLOTTE 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
FRANCES 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
ELEANOR 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
PEARL 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
RUTH 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
VERNE 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
MYRNA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
KATHERINE 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
SYLVIA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
NORA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
HELEN 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
DOROTHY 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
OLIVIA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
FLORA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
6/27 1 1 0 1 0 0 0 0 0
3/2 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0
4/12 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 0
9/26 1 0 1 1 1 0 0 0 0
2/25 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1
5/19 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 0
3/15 0 1 1 1 1 0 1 0 1
9/16 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1
4/8 1 0 1 0 0 0 0 1 1
6/10 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
2/23 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
4/7 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
11/21 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
8/3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
VERNE MYRNA KATHERINE SYLVIA NORA HELEN DOROTHY OLIVIA FLORA 6/27 3/2
EVELYN 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1
LAURA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1
THERESA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1
BRENDA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0
CHARLOTTE 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
FRANCES 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
ELEANOR 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
PEARL 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
RUTH 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
VERNE 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
MYRNA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
KATHERINE 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
SYLVIA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
NORA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
HELEN 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
DOROTHY 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
OLIVIA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
FLORA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
6/27 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
3/2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
4/12 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
9/26 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
2/25 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
5/19 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0
3/15 1 0 0 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0
9/16 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 0 0 0 0
4/8 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 0 0
6/10 0 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0
2/23 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 1 1 0 0
4/7 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0
11/21 0 0 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0
8/3 0 0 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0
4/12 9/26 2/25 5/19 3/15 9/16 4/8 6/10 2/23 4/7 11/21 8/3
EVELYN 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 0
LAURA 1 0 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0
THERESA 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0
BRENDA 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0
CHARLOTTE 1 1 1 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
FRANCES 1 0 1 1 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0
ELEANOR 0 0 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0
PEARL 0 0 0 1 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 0
RUTH 0 0 1 0 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0
VERNE 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 0 0 1 0 0
MYRNA 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 0 1 0 0
KATHERINE 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 0 1 1 1
SYLVIA 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1
NORA 0 0 0 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1
HELEN 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 1 1 1 0 0
DOROTHY 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 0
OLIVIA 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 1 0 0 0
FLORA 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 1 0 0 0
6/27 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
3/2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
4/12 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
9/26 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
2/25 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
5/19 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
3/15 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
9/16 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
4/8 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
6/10 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
2/23 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
4/7 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
11/21 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
8/3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
This bipartite adjacency matrix \(\mathbf{B}\) is of dimensions \((M + N) \times (M + N)\), which is \((18 + 14) \times (18 + 14) = 32 \times 32\) in the Southern Women data; it has the following block structure (Fouss, Saerens, and Shimbo 2016, 12):
\[ \mathbf{B} = \left[ \begin{matrix} \mathbf{O}_{M \times M} & \mathbf{A}_{M \times N} \\ \mathbf{A}^T_{N \times M} & \mathbf{O}_{N \times N} \end{matrix} \right] \]
Where \(\mathbf{O}\) is just the all zeros matrix of the relevant dimensions, and \(\mathbf{A}\) is the bi-adjacency (affiliation) matrix as defined earlier. Thus, the bipartite adjacency matrix necessarily has two big diagonal “zero blocks” in it (upper-left and lower-right) corresponding to where the links between nodes in the same set would be (but necessarily aren’t because this is a two-mode network). The non-zero blocks are just the affiliation matrix (upper-right) and its transpose(lower-left).
Bipartiteness as “Anti-Community”
Recall from the previous handout, that community structure is defined by clusters of nodes that have more connections among themselves than they do with outsiders. If you think about it, a bipartite graph has the opposite of this going on. Nodes of the same type have zero connections among themselves, and they have all their connections with nodes of the other group!
So that means that bipartite structure is the mirror image of community structure (in the two group case). This also means that if we were to compute the modularity of a bipartite graph, using the node type as the grouping variable we should get the theoretical minimum of this measure (which you may recall is \(Q = -\frac{1}{2}\)).
Let’s try it out, by computing the modularity from the bipartite adjacency matrix of the Southern Women data, using node type as the grouping variable:
And indeed, we recover the theoretical minimum value of the modularity (Brandes et al. 2007, 173)! This also means that this method can be used to test whether a graph is bipartite, or whether any network approximates bipartiteness (Newman 2006, 13). Values that are close to \(-0.5\) would indicate that the network in question has bipartite structure.
Basic Two-Mode Network Statistics
We can calculate some basic network statistics from the affiliation (bi-adjacency) matrix. We have two number of nodes to calculate, but only one quantity for the number of edges.
The number of nodes on the people side \(N\) is just the number of rows of \(A\):
And the number of events/groups \(M\) is just the number of columns:
Finally, the number of edges \(E\) is just the sum of all the entries of \(A\):
Note that if you were to use the igraph
function vcount
on the original graph object, you get the wrong answer:
That’s because vcount
is working with the \(32 \times 32\) regular adjacency matrix, not the bi-adjacency matrix. Here, vcount
is returning the total number of nodes in the graph summing across the two sets, which is \(M + N\).
If you wanted to get the right answer for each set of edges from the regular igraph
graph object, you could use the type
node attribute we defined earlier along with the subgraph
function:
Which gives us the number of women. For the events we do the same thing:
However, because there’s only one set of edges, ecount
still gives us the right answer:
Which is the same as:
Degree Statistics
Because we have two sets of degrees, all the basic degree statistics in the network double up. So we have two mean degrees, two maximum degrees, and two minimum degree to take care of:
So we have:
[1] 4.9
[1] 6.4
[1] 8
[1] 14
[1] 2
[1] 3
However, note that because there’s only one set of undirected edges, the total number of edges incident to each node in each of the two sets is always going to be the same.
That means that there’s only one sum of degrees. So the sum of degrees for people:
Is the same as the sum of degrees of events:
Note that in a bipartite graph, therefore, the sum of degrees of nodes in each node set is equal to the \(|E|\), the number of edges in the graph!
Density
As we saw in the case of one-mode networks, one of the most basic network statistics that can be derived from the above quantities is the density (observed number of edges divided by maximum possible number of edges in the graph).
In a two-mode network, density is given by:
\[ d = \frac{|E|}{N \times M} \]
Where \(|E|\) is the number of edges in the network. In our case we can compute the density as follows:
Degree Centrality
In a two-mode network, there are two degree sets, each corresponding to one set of nodes. For the people, in this case, their degree (centrality) is just the number of events they attend, and for the groups, it’s just the number of people that attend each event.
As we have already seen, we can get each from the affiliation matrix. The degree of the people are just the row sums:
EVELYN LAURA THERESA BRENDA CHARLOTTE FRANCES ELEANOR PEARL
8 7 8 7 4 4 4 3
RUTH VERNE MYRNA KATHERINE SYLVIA NORA HELEN DOROTHY
4 4 4 6 7 8 5 2
OLIVIA FLORA
2 2
And the degree of the events are just the column sums:
6/27 3/2 4/12 9/26 2/25 5/19 3/15 9/16 4/8 6/10 2/23 4/7 11/21
3 3 6 4 8 8 10 14 12 5 4 6 3
8/3
3
The igraph
function degree
will also give us the right answer, but in the form of a single vector including both people and events:
EVELYN LAURA THERESA BRENDA CHARLOTTE FRANCES ELEANOR PEARL
8 7 8 7 4 4 4 3
RUTH VERNE MYRNA KATHERINE SYLVIA NORA HELEN DOROTHY
4 4 4 6 7 8 5 2
OLIVIA FLORA 6/27 3/2 4/12 9/26 2/25 5/19
2 2 3 3 6 4 8 8
3/15 9/16 4/8 6/10 2/23 4/7 11/21 8/3
10 14 12 5 4 6 3 3
As Borgatti and Everett (1997) note, if we want normalized degree centrality measures, we need to divide by either \(M\) (for people) or \(N\) (for events). That is, for people we use the number of events as the norm (as this is the theoretical maximum) and for events the number of people.
So for people, normalized degree is:
EVELYN LAURA THERESA BRENDA CHARLOTTE FRANCES ELEANOR PEARL
0.571 0.500 0.571 0.500 0.286 0.286 0.286 0.214
RUTH VERNE MYRNA KATHERINE SYLVIA NORA HELEN DOROTHY
0.286 0.286 0.286 0.429 0.500 0.571 0.357 0.143
OLIVIA FLORA
0.143 0.143
And for events:
6/27 3/2 4/12 9/26 2/25 5/19 3/15 9/16 4/8 6/10 2/23 4/7 11/21
0.167 0.167 0.333 0.222 0.444 0.444 0.556 0.778 0.667 0.278 0.222 0.333 0.167
8/3
0.167
Or with igraph
:
EVELYN LAURA THERESA BRENDA CHARLOTTE FRANCES ELEANOR PEARL
0.571 0.500 0.571 0.500 0.286 0.286 0.286 0.214
RUTH VERNE MYRNA KATHERINE SYLVIA NORA HELEN DOROTHY
0.286 0.286 0.286 0.429 0.500 0.571 0.357 0.143
OLIVIA FLORA 6/27 3/2 4/12 9/26 2/25 5/19
0.143 0.143 0.167 0.167 0.333 0.222 0.444 0.444
3/15 9/16 4/8 6/10 2/23 4/7 11/21 8/3
0.556 0.778 0.667 0.278 0.222 0.333 0.167 0.167
Geodesic Distances
Geodesic distances work a bit different in two-mode networks because of the only between-node-sets edges restriction.
For instance, the minimum geodesic distance \(g_{ii'}\) between two people is two (a person cannot be adjacent to another person), but it is one between a person and a group (if the person is a member of the group).
In the same way, a group \(g\) cannot be at geodesic distance less than three from a person \(p*\) who is not a member, because the shortest path is \(g-p-g^*-p^*\).
That is, there has to be some other group \(g^*\) shared between a member \(p\) of the focal group \(g\) and another person \(p^*\) for the shortest path between \(g\) and the non-member \(p^*\) to exist, and that involves three links at minimum: \(g-p\), \(p-g^*\), and \(g^*-p^*\). This means that the links in paths in two-mode networks always alternate between persons and group nodes.
Beyond that geodesic distances work the same way. In igraph
when we use the distances
function on a bipartite graph, we get:
EVELYN LAURA THERESA BRENDA CHARLOTTE FRANCES ELEANOR PEARL RUTH
EVELYN 0 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2
LAURA 2 0 2 2 2 2 2 2 2
THERESA 2 2 0 2 2 2 2 2 2
BRENDA 2 2 2 0 2 2 2 2 2
CHARLOTTE 2 2 2 2 0 2 2 4 2
FRANCES 2 2 2 2 2 0 2 2 2
VERNE MYRNA KATHERINE SYLVIA NORA HELEN DOROTHY OLIVIA FLORA 6/27 3/2
EVELYN 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1
LAURA 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 4 4 1 1
THERESA 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 3 1
BRENDA 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 4 4 1 3
CHARLOTTE 2 4 4 2 2 2 4 4 4 3 3
FRANCES 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 4 4 3 3
4/12 9/26 2/25 5/19 3/15 9/16 4/8 6/10 2/23 4/7 11/21 8/3
EVELYN 1 1 1 1 3 1 1 3 3 3 3 3
LAURA 1 3 1 1 1 1 3 3 3 3 3 3
THERESA 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 3 3 3 3 3
BRENDA 1 1 1 1 1 1 3 3 3 3 3 3
CHARLOTTE 1 1 1 3 1 3 3 3 3 3 3 3
FRANCES 1 3 1 1 3 1 3 3 3 3 3 3
EVELYN LAURA THERESA BRENDA CHARLOTTE FRANCES ELEANOR PEARL RUTH VERNE
4/8 1 3 1 3 3 3 3 1 1 1
6/10 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3
2/23 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3
4/7 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 1
11/21 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3
8/3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3
MYRNA KATHERINE SYLVIA NORA HELEN DOROTHY OLIVIA FLORA 6/27 3/2 4/12 9/26
4/8 1 1 1 1 3 1 1 1 2 2 2 2
6/10 1 1 1 1 1 3 3 3 4 4 4 4
2/23 3 3 3 1 1 3 1 1 4 4 4 4
4/7 1 1 1 1 1 3 3 3 4 4 4 4
11/21 3 1 1 1 3 3 3 3 4 4 4 4
8/3 3 1 1 1 3 3 3 3 4 4 4 4
2/25 5/19 3/15 9/16 4/8 6/10 2/23 4/7 11/21 8/3
4/8 2 2 2 2 0 2 2 2 2 2
6/10 4 2 2 2 2 0 2 2 2 2
2/23 4 2 2 2 2 2 0 2 2 2
4/7 4 2 2 2 2 2 2 0 2 2
11/21 4 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 0 2
8/3 4 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 0
Which is a square matrix of dimensions \((M + N) \times (M + N)\); that’s \((18 + 14) \times (18 + 14) = 32 \times 32\) in our case.
We can check in R
:
As we can see in the distance matrix, distances between nodes in the same set are even \(g_{ii'|jj'} = \{2, 4, \ldots\}\) but distances in nodes in different sets are odd \(g_{ij|ji} = \{1, 3, \ldots\}\). Beyond this hiccup, distances can be interpreted in the same way as one-mode networks.
Closeness Centrality in two-mode Networks
This means that (unnormalized) closeness centrality works the same way as it does in regular networks:
EVELYN LAURA THERESA BRENDA CHARLOTTE FRANCES ELEANOR PEARL
0.017 0.015 0.017 0.015 0.013 0.014 0.014 0.014
RUTH VERNE MYRNA KATHERINE SYLVIA NORA HELEN DOROTHY
0.015 0.015 0.014 0.015 0.016 0.017 0.015 0.014
OLIVIA FLORA 6/27 3/2 4/12 9/26 2/25 5/19
0.012 0.012 0.012 0.012 0.013 0.012 0.014 0.016
3/15 9/16 4/8 6/10 2/23 4/7 11/21 8/3
0.017 0.019 0.018 0.013 0.012 0.013 0.012 0.012
Which is just the inverse of the sums of the distances matrix for people and groups counting their geodesic distances to nodes of both sets.
However, as Borgatti and Everett (1997) note, if we want normalized closeness centralities, we can’t use the off-the-shelf normalization for one-mode networks in igraph
(\(n-1\)) as it will give us non-sense results because now we have two sets of nodes.
Instead, we need to normalize the closeness score for each node set by its theoretical maximum for each node set.
For people, this is:
\[ N + 2(M - 1) \]
And for groups/events this same quantity is:
\[ M + 2(N - 1) \]
The basic idea is that nodes can be at minimum geodesic distance \(g = 1\) from nodes of the other set (for people, groups; for groups, people) and at minimum distance \(g = 2\) from nodes of their own set, with their own presence eliminated by subtraction (Borgatti and Everett 1997).
In our case, we create a normalization vector with these quantities of length \(M + N\):
And normalized closeness is:
EVELYN LAURA THERESA BRENDA CHARLOTTE FRANCES ELEANOR PEARL
0.800 0.727 0.800 0.727 0.600 0.667 0.667 0.667
RUTH VERNE MYRNA KATHERINE SYLVIA NORA HELEN DOROTHY
0.706 0.706 0.686 0.727 0.774 0.800 0.727 0.649
OLIVIA FLORA 6/27 3/2 4/12 9/26 2/25 5/19
0.585 0.585 0.524 0.524 0.564 0.537 0.595 0.688
3/15 9/16 4/8 6/10 2/23 4/7 11/21 8/3
0.733 0.846 0.786 0.550 0.537 0.564 0.524 0.524
Which are the same numbers in Borgatti and Everett (1997, table 1, column 6).
Betweenness Centrality in two-mode Networks
As Borgatti and Everett (1997) also note, the normalizations for betweenness centrality in the two-mode case are a bit more involved. This is because they depend on which node set is larger than the other.
For the larger node set, which in our case is the people, the normalization is:
\[ 2(M-1)(N-1) \]
For the smaller node set, which in our case is the groups/events, the normalization is:
\[ \frac{1}{2}(N)(N-1)+\frac{1}{2}(M-1)(M-2)+(M-1)(N-1) \]
Remember that you have to switch this around if you are analyzing a network with more groups than people.
Creating the relevant vectors:
And normalized betweenness is:
EVELYN LAURA THERESA BRENDA CHARLOTTE FRANCES ELEANOR PEARL
9.72 5.17 8.82 4.98 1.07 1.08 0.95 0.68
RUTH VERNE MYRNA KATHERINE SYLVIA NORA HELEN DOROTHY
1.69 1.58 1.65 4.77 7.22 11.42 4.27 0.20
OLIVIA FLORA 6/27 3/2 4/12 9/26 2/25 5/19
0.51 0.51 0.22 0.21 1.84 0.78 3.80 6.56
3/15 9/16 4/8 6/10 2/23 4/7 11/21 8/3
13.07 24.60 22.75 1.15 1.98 1.83 0.23 0.23
Which are (with some slight differences and rounding errors) the same numbers in Borgatti and Everett (1997, table 2, column 3).
The Duality of Persons and Groups
Remember that in the one-mode case, multiplying the adjacency matrix times its transpose yields the common neighbors matrix \(\mathbf{M}\):
\[ \mathbf{M} = \mathbf{A}\mathbf{A}^T \]
As famously noted by Breiger (1974), doing the same for the affiliation matrix of a two-mode network also returns the common-neighbors matrix, but because objects in one mode can only connect to objects in another mode, this also reveals the duality of persons and groups: The connections between people are made up of the groups they share, and the connections between groups are revealed by the groups they share.
Thus, computing the common neighbors matrix for both persons and groups (also called the projection of the two-mode network into each of its modes) produces a one-mode similarity matrix between people and groups, where the similarities are defined by the number of objects in the other mode that they share.
So for the people the relevant projection is:
\[ \mathbf{P} = \mathbf{A}\mathbf{A}^T \]
And for the groups:
\[ \mathbf{G} = \mathbf{A}^T\mathbf{A} \]
Which in our case yields:
EVELYN LAURA THERESA BRENDA CHARLOTTE FRANCES ELEANOR PEARL RUTH
EVELYN 8 6 7 6 3 4 3 3 3
LAURA 6 7 6 6 3 4 4 2 3
THERESA 7 6 8 6 4 4 4 3 4
BRENDA 6 6 6 7 4 4 4 2 3
CHARLOTTE 3 3 4 4 4 2 2 0 2
FRANCES 4 4 4 4 2 4 3 2 2
ELEANOR 3 4 4 4 2 3 4 2 3
PEARL 3 2 3 2 0 2 2 3 2
RUTH 3 3 4 3 2 2 3 2 4
VERNE 2 2 3 2 1 1 2 2 3
MYRNA 2 1 2 1 0 1 1 2 2
KATHERINE 2 1 2 1 0 1 1 2 2
SYLVIA 2 2 3 2 1 1 2 2 3
NORA 2 2 3 2 1 1 2 2 2
HELEN 1 2 2 2 1 1 2 1 2
DOROTHY 2 1 2 1 0 1 1 2 2
OLIVIA 1 0 1 0 0 0 0 1 1
FLORA 1 0 1 0 0 0 0 1 1
VERNE MYRNA KATHERINE SYLVIA NORA HELEN DOROTHY OLIVIA FLORA
EVELYN 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 1
LAURA 2 1 1 2 2 2 1 0 0
THERESA 3 2 2 3 3 2 2 1 1
BRENDA 2 1 1 2 2 2 1 0 0
CHARLOTTE 1 0 0 1 1 1 0 0 0
FRANCES 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0
ELEANOR 2 1 1 2 2 2 1 0 0
PEARL 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 1
RUTH 3 2 2 3 2 2 2 1 1
VERNE 4 3 3 4 3 3 2 1 1
MYRNA 3 4 4 4 3 3 2 1 1
KATHERINE 3 4 6 6 5 3 2 1 1
SYLVIA 4 4 6 7 6 4 2 1 1
NORA 3 3 5 6 8 4 1 2 2
HELEN 3 3 3 4 4 5 1 1 1
DOROTHY 2 2 2 2 1 1 2 1 1
OLIVIA 1 1 1 1 2 1 1 2 2
FLORA 1 1 1 1 2 1 1 2 2
6/27 3/2 4/12 9/26 2/25 5/19 3/15 9/16 4/8 6/10 2/23 4/7 11/21 8/3
6/27 3 2 3 2 3 3 2 3 1 0 0 0 0 0
3/2 2 3 3 2 3 3 2 3 2 0 0 0 0 0
4/12 3 3 6 4 6 5 4 5 2 0 0 0 0 0
9/26 2 2 4 4 4 3 3 3 2 0 0 0 0 0
2/25 3 3 6 4 8 6 6 7 3 0 0 0 0 0
5/19 3 3 5 3 6 8 5 7 4 1 1 1 1 1
3/15 2 2 4 3 6 5 10 8 5 3 2 4 2 2
9/16 3 3 5 3 7 7 8 14 9 4 1 5 2 2
4/8 1 2 2 2 3 4 5 9 12 4 3 5 3 3
6/10 0 0 0 0 0 1 3 4 4 5 2 5 3 3
2/23 0 0 0 0 0 1 2 1 3 2 4 2 1 1
4/7 0 0 0 0 0 1 4 5 5 5 2 6 3 3
11/21 0 0 0 0 0 1 2 2 3 3 1 3 3 3
8/3 0 0 0 0 0 1 2 2 3 3 1 3 3 3
The off-diagonal entries of these square person by person (group by group) matrices is the number of groups (people) shared by each person (group) and the diagonals are the number of memberships of each person (the size of each group/event).
In igraph
the relevant function is called bipartite_projection
. It takes a graph as an input and returns a list containing igraph
graph objects of both projections by default:
set.seed(123)
plot(G.p,
vertex.size=8, vertex.frame.color="lightgray",
vertex.label.dist=2, edge.curved=0.2,
vertex.label.cex = 1.25, edge.color = "lightgray",
edge.width = E(G.p)$weight)
set.seed(123)
plot(G.g,
vertex.size=8, vertex.frame.color="lightgray",
vertex.label.dist=2, edge.curved=0.2,
vertex.label.cex = 1.25, edge.color = "lightgray",
edge.width = E(G.g)$weight)
Which produces a binarized undirected graph of each projection.
The actual shared memberships and shared members are stored as an attribute of each edge called weight
used in the plotting code above to set the edge.width
:
$weight
[1] 6 6 7 3 4 3 3 3 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 1 6 6 3 4 4 3 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 6 4 4 4 4 3
[38] 3 3 3 2 2 2 2 1 1 4 4 4 3 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 1 1 1 1 3 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 1
[75] 1 3 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 1 3 3 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 4 3 3 3 3 2 1 1
[112] 4 4 3 2 3 1 1 6 3 2 5 1 1 6 4 2 1 1 4 1 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 2
$weight
[1] 2 3 2 3 3 3 1 2 3 2 3 3 3 2 2 4 6 5 5 2 4 4 3 3 2 3 6 7 3 6 7 4 5 1 1 1 1 1
[39] 8 5 4 3 2 2 2 9 5 4 2 2 1 5 4 3 3 3 5 3 3 2 2 1 1 3 3 3
So to get the weighted projection matrix, we need to type:
EVELYN LAURA THERESA BRENDA CHARLOTTE FRANCES ELEANOR PEARL RUTH
EVELYN 0 6 7 6 3 4 3 3 3
LAURA 6 0 6 6 3 4 4 2 3
THERESA 7 6 0 6 4 4 4 3 4
BRENDA 6 6 6 0 4 4 4 2 3
CHARLOTTE 3 3 4 4 0 2 2 0 2
FRANCES 4 4 4 4 2 0 3 2 2
ELEANOR 3 4 4 4 2 3 0 2 3
PEARL 3 2 3 2 0 2 2 0 2
RUTH 3 3 4 3 2 2 3 2 0
VERNE 2 2 3 2 1 1 2 2 3
MYRNA 2 1 2 1 0 1 1 2 2
KATHERINE 2 1 2 1 0 1 1 2 2
SYLVIA 2 2 3 2 1 1 2 2 3
NORA 2 2 3 2 1 1 2 2 2
HELEN 1 2 2 2 1 1 2 1 2
DOROTHY 2 1 2 1 0 1 1 2 2
OLIVIA 1 0 1 0 0 0 0 1 1
FLORA 1 0 1 0 0 0 0 1 1
VERNE MYRNA KATHERINE SYLVIA NORA HELEN DOROTHY OLIVIA FLORA
EVELYN 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 1
LAURA 2 1 1 2 2 2 1 0 0
THERESA 3 2 2 3 3 2 2 1 1
BRENDA 2 1 1 2 2 2 1 0 0
CHARLOTTE 1 0 0 1 1 1 0 0 0
FRANCES 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0
ELEANOR 2 1 1 2 2 2 1 0 0
PEARL 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 1
RUTH 3 2 2 3 2 2 2 1 1
VERNE 0 3 3 4 3 3 2 1 1
MYRNA 3 0 4 4 3 3 2 1 1
KATHERINE 3 4 0 6 5 3 2 1 1
SYLVIA 4 4 6 0 6 4 2 1 1
NORA 3 3 5 6 0 4 1 2 2
HELEN 3 3 3 4 4 0 1 1 1
DOROTHY 2 2 2 2 1 1 0 1 1
OLIVIA 1 1 1 1 2 1 1 0 2
FLORA 1 1 1 1 2 1 1 2 0
6/27 3/2 4/12 9/26 2/25 5/19 3/15 9/16 4/8 6/10 2/23 4/7 11/21 8/3
6/27 0 2 3 2 3 3 2 3 1 0 0 0 0 0
3/2 2 0 3 2 3 3 2 3 2 0 0 0 0 0
4/12 3 3 0 4 6 5 4 5 2 0 0 0 0 0
9/26 2 2 4 0 4 3 3 3 2 0 0 0 0 0
2/25 3 3 6 4 0 6 6 7 3 0 0 0 0 0
5/19 3 3 5 3 6 0 5 7 4 1 1 1 1 1
3/15 2 2 4 3 6 5 0 8 5 3 2 4 2 2
9/16 3 3 5 3 7 7 8 0 9 4 1 5 2 2
4/8 1 2 2 2 3 4 5 9 0 4 3 5 3 3
6/10 0 0 0 0 0 1 3 4 4 0 2 5 3 3
2/23 0 0 0 0 0 1 2 1 3 2 0 2 1 1
4/7 0 0 0 0 0 1 4 5 5 5 2 0 3 3
11/21 0 0 0 0 0 1 2 2 3 3 1 3 0 3
8/3 0 0 0 0 0 1 2 2 3 3 1 3 3 0
Note that because both G.p
and G.g
are weighted graphs we can calculate the weighted version of degree for both persons and groups from them (sometimes called the vertex strength).
In igraph
we can do this as follows:
EVELYN LAURA THERESA BRENDA CHARLOTTE FRANCES ELEANOR PEARL
50 45 57 46 24 32 36 31
RUTH VERNE MYRNA KATHERINE SYLVIA NORA HELEN DOROTHY
40 38 33 37 46 43 34 24
OLIVIA FLORA
14 14
6/27 3/2 4/12 9/26 2/25 5/19 3/15 9/16 4/8 6/10 2/23 4/7 11/21
19 20 32 23 38 41 48 59 46 25 13 28 18
8/3
18
Interestingly, as noted by Faust (1997, 167), there is a mathematical connection between the strength of each vertex in the weighted projection and the centrality of the nodes from the other set they are connected to:
For people, the vertex strength is equal to the sum of the sizes of the groups they belong to minus their own degree.
For groups, the vertex strength is equal to the sum of the memberships of the people that belong to them, minus their own size.
We can verify this relationship for \(EVELYN\):
sum.size.evelyn <- sum(A["EVELYN", ] * degree(g)[which(V(g)$type == TRUE)]) #sum of the sizes of the groups Evelyn belongs to
sum.size.evelyn - degree(g)[which(V(g)$name == "EVELYN")]
EVELYN
50
Which is indeed Evelyn’s vertex strength.
Dually, the same relation applies to groups:
sum.mem.6.27 <- sum(A[, "6/27"] * degree(g)[which(V(g)$type == FALSE)]) #sum of the memberships of people in the first group
sum.mem.6.27 - degree(g)[which(V(g)$name == "6/27")]
6/27
19
Which is indeed the vertex strength of the event held on 6/27.
Normalized Vertex Similarity Metrics
Note that the one-mode projections are unnormalized similarity matrices just like in the case of regular networks. That means that if we have the degrees of nodes in each mode, we can transform this matrix into any of the normalized vertex similarity metrics we discussed before, including Jaccard, Cosine, Dice, LHN, and so on.
Thus repackaging our vertex similarity function for the two-mode case, we have:
vertex.sim <- function(x) {
A <- as.matrix(as_biadjacency_matrix(x))
M <- nrow(A) #number of persons
N <- ncol(A) #number of groups
p.d <- rowSums(A) #person degrees
g.d <- colSums(A) #group degrees
P <- A %*% t(A) #person projection
G <- t(A) %*% A #group projection
J.p <- diag(1, M, M)
J.g <- diag(1, N, N)
C.p <- diag(1, M, M)
C.g <- diag(1, N, N)
D.p <- diag(1, M, M)
D.g <- diag(1, N, N)
L.p <- diag(1, M, M)
L.g <- diag(1, N, N)
for (i in 1:M) {
for (j in 1:M) {
if (i < j) {
J.p[i,j] <- P[i,j]/(P[i,j] + p.d[i] + p.d[j])
J.p[j,i] <- P[i,j]/(P[i,j] + p.d[i] + p.d[j])
C.p[i,j] <- P[i,j]/(sqrt(p.d[i] * p.d[j]))
C.p[j,i] <- P[i,j]/(sqrt(p.d[i] * p.d[j]))
D.p[i,j] <- (2*P[i,j])/(2*P[i,j] + p.d[i] + p.d[j])
D.p[j,i] <- (2*P[i,j])/(2*P[i,j] + p.d[i] + p.d[j])
L.p[i,j] <- P[i,j]/(p.d[i] * p.d[j])
L.p[j,i] <- P[i,j]/(p.d[i] * p.d[j])
}
}
}
for (i in 1:N) {
for (j in 1:N) {
if (i < j) {
J.g[i,j] <- G[i,j]/(G[i,j] + g.d[i] + g.d[j])
J.g[j,i] <- G[i,j]/(G[i,j] + g.d[i] + g.d[j])
C.g[i,j] <- G[i,j]/(sqrt(g.d[i] * g.d[j]))
C.g[j,i] <- G[i,j]/(sqrt(g.d[i] * g.d[j]))
D.g[i,j] <- (2*G[i,j])/(2*G[i,j] + g.d[i] + g.d[j])
D.g[j,i] <- (2*G[i,j])/(2*G[i,j] + g.d[i] + g.d[j])
L.g[i,j] <- G[i,j]/(g.d[i] * g.d[j])
L.g[j,i] <- G[i,j]/(g.d[i] * g.d[j])
}
}
}
return(list(J.p = J.p, C.p = C.p, D.p = D.p, L.p = L.p,
J.g = J.g, C.g = C.g, D.g = D.g, L.g = L.g))
}
Using this function to compute the Jaccard similarity between people yields:
EVELYN LAURA THERESA BRENDA CHARLOTTE FRANCES ELEANOR PEARL RUTH
EVELYN 1.00 0.29 0.30 0.29 0.20 0.25 0.20 0.21 0.20
LAURA 0.29 1.00 0.29 0.30 0.21 0.27 0.27 0.17 0.21
THERESA 0.30 0.29 1.00 0.29 0.25 0.25 0.25 0.21 0.25
BRENDA 0.29 0.30 0.29 1.00 0.27 0.27 0.27 0.17 0.21
CHARLOTTE 0.20 0.21 0.25 0.27 1.00 0.20 0.20 0.00 0.20
FRANCES 0.25 0.27 0.25 0.27 0.20 1.00 0.27 0.22 0.20
ELEANOR 0.20 0.27 0.25 0.27 0.20 0.27 1.00 0.22 0.27
PEARL 0.21 0.17 0.21 0.17 0.00 0.22 0.22 1.00 0.22
RUTH 0.20 0.21 0.25 0.21 0.20 0.20 0.27 0.22 1.00
VERNE 0.14 0.15 0.20 0.15 0.11 0.11 0.20 0.22 0.27
MYRNA 0.14 0.08 0.14 0.08 0.00 0.11 0.11 0.22 0.20
KATHERINE 0.12 0.07 0.12 0.07 0.00 0.09 0.09 0.18 0.17
SYLVIA 0.12 0.12 0.17 0.12 0.08 0.08 0.15 0.17 0.21
NORA 0.11 0.12 0.16 0.12 0.08 0.08 0.14 0.15 0.14
HELEN 0.07 0.14 0.13 0.14 0.10 0.10 0.18 0.11 0.18
DOROTHY 0.17 0.10 0.17 0.10 0.00 0.14 0.14 0.29 0.25
OLIVIA 0.09 0.00 0.09 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.17 0.14
FLORA 0.09 0.00 0.09 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.17 0.14
VERNE MYRNA KATHERINE SYLVIA NORA HELEN DOROTHY OLIVIA FLORA
EVELYN 0.14 0.14 0.12 0.12 0.11 0.07 0.17 0.09 0.09
LAURA 0.15 0.08 0.07 0.12 0.12 0.14 0.10 0.00 0.00
THERESA 0.20 0.14 0.12 0.17 0.16 0.13 0.17 0.09 0.09
BRENDA 0.15 0.08 0.07 0.12 0.12 0.14 0.10 0.00 0.00
CHARLOTTE 0.11 0.00 0.00 0.08 0.08 0.10 0.00 0.00 0.00
FRANCES 0.11 0.11 0.09 0.08 0.08 0.10 0.14 0.00 0.00
ELEANOR 0.20 0.11 0.09 0.15 0.14 0.18 0.14 0.00 0.00
PEARL 0.22 0.22 0.18 0.17 0.15 0.11 0.29 0.17 0.17
RUTH 0.27 0.20 0.17 0.21 0.14 0.18 0.25 0.14 0.14
VERNE 1.00 0.27 0.23 0.27 0.20 0.25 0.25 0.14 0.14
MYRNA 0.27 1.00 0.29 0.27 0.20 0.25 0.25 0.14 0.14
KATHERINE 0.23 0.29 1.00 0.32 0.26 0.21 0.20 0.11 0.11
SYLVIA 0.27 0.27 0.32 1.00 0.29 0.25 0.18 0.10 0.10
NORA 0.20 0.20 0.26 0.29 1.00 0.24 0.09 0.17 0.17
HELEN 0.25 0.25 0.21 0.25 0.24 1.00 0.12 0.12 0.12
DOROTHY 0.25 0.25 0.20 0.18 0.09 0.12 1.00 0.20 0.20
OLIVIA 0.14 0.14 0.11 0.10 0.17 0.12 0.20 1.00 0.33
FLORA 0.14 0.14 0.11 0.10 0.17 0.12 0.20 0.33 1.00
Structural Equivalence
And, of course, once we have a similarity we can cluster nodes based on approximate structural equivalence by transforming proximities to distances:
And for events:
J.g <- vertex.sim(g)$J.g
rownames(J.g) <- colnames(A)
colnames(J.g) <- colnames(A)
D <- as.dist(1- J.g)
hc.g <- hclust(D, method = "ward.D2")
plot(hc.g)
We can then derive cluster memberships for people and groups from the hclust
object:
EVELYN LAURA THERESA BRENDA CHARLOTTE FRANCES ELEANOR PEARL
1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2
RUTH VERNE DOROTHY MYRNA KATHERINE SYLVIA NORA HELEN
2 2 2 3 3 3 3 3
OLIVIA FLORA
4 4
6/27 3/2 4/12 9/26 2/25 5/19 3/15 9/16 4/8 6/10 2/23 4/7 11/21
1 1 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 3 3 3 3
8/3
3
And finally we can block the original affiliation matrix, as recommended by Everett and Borgatti (2013, 210, table 5):
library(ggcorrplot)
p <- ggcorrplot(t(A[names(clus.p), names(clus.g)]),
colors = c("white", "white", "red"))
p <- p + theme(legend.position = "none",
axis.text.y = element_text(size = 8),
axis.text.x = element_text(size = 8, angle = 0),
)
p <- p + scale_x_discrete(position = "top")
p <- p + geom_hline(yintercept = 7.5, linewidth = 2, color = "blue")
p <- p + geom_hline(yintercept = 11.5, linewidth = 2, color = "blue")
p <- p + geom_hline(yintercept = 16.5, linewidth = 2, color = "blue")
p <- p + geom_vline(xintercept = 6.5, linewidth = 2, color = "blue")
p <- p + geom_vline(xintercept = 9.5, linewidth = 2, color = "blue")
p
Which reveals a number of almost complete (one-blocks) and almost null (zero-blocks) in the social structure, with a reduced image matrix that looks like:
library(kableExtra)
IM <- matrix(0, 4, 3)
IM[1, ] <- c(0, 1, 0)
IM[2, ] <- c(0, 1, 1)
IM[3, ] <- c(0, 1, 0)
IM[4, ] <- c(1, 1, 0)
rownames(IM) <- c("P.Block1", "P.Block2", "P.Block3", "P.Block4")
colnames(IM) <- c("E.Block1", "E.Block2", "E.Block3")
kbl(IM, format = "html", , align = "c") %>%
column_spec(1, bold = TRUE) %>%
kable_styling(full_width = TRUE,
bootstrap_options = c("hover", "condensed", "responsive"))
E.Block1 | E.Block2 | E.Block3 | |
---|---|---|---|
P.Block1 | 0 | 1 | 0 |
P.Block2 | 0 | 1 | 1 |
P.Block3 | 0 | 1 | 0 |
P.Block4 | 1 | 1 | 0 |
Generalized Vertex Similarity
Recall that vertex similarity works using the principle of structural equivalence: Two people are similar if the choose the same objects (groups), and two objects (groups) are similar if they are chosen by the same people.
We can, like we did in the one mode case, be after a more general version of similarity, which says that: Two people are similar if they choose similar objects, and two objects are similar if they are chosen by similar people.
This leads to the same problem setup that inspired the SimRank approach (Jeh and Widom 2002).
A function to compute the SimRank similarity between nodes in a two mode network goes as follows:
TM.SimRank <- function(A, C = 0.8, iter = 10) {
nr <- nrow(A)
nc <- ncol(A)
dr <- rowSums(A)
dc <- colSums(A)
Sr <- diag(1, nr, nr) #baseline similarity: every node maximally similar to themselves
Sc <- diag(1, nc, nc) #baseline similarity: every node maximally similar to themselves
rn <- rownames(A)
cn <- colnames(A)
rownames(Sr) <- rn
colnames(Sr) <- rn
rownames(Sc) <- cn
colnames(Sc) <- cn
m <- 1
while(m < iter) {
Sr.pre <- Sr
Sc.pre <- Sc
for(i in 1:nr) {
for(j in 1:nr) {
if (i != j) {
a <- names(which(A[i, ] == 1)) #objects chosen by i
b <- names(which(A[j, ] == 1)) #objects chosen by j
Scij <- 0
for (k in a) {
for (l in b) {
Scij <- Scij + Sc[k, l] #i's similarity to j
}
}
Sr[i, j] <- C/(dr[i] * dr[j]) * Scij
}
}
}
for(i in 1:nc) {
for(j in 1:nc) {
if (i != j) {
a <- names(which(A[, i] == 1)) #people who chose object i
b <- names(which(A[, j] == 1)) #people who chose object j
Srij <- 0
for (k in a) {
for (l in b) {
Srij <- Srij + Sr[k, l] #i's similarity to j
}
}
Sc[i, j] <- C/(dc[i] * dc[j]) * Srij
}
}
}
m <- m + 1
}
return(list(Sr = Sr, Sc = Sc))
}
This function takes the bi-adjacency matrix \(\mathbf{A}\) as input and returns two similarity matrices: One for the people (row objects) and the other one for the groups (column objects).
Here’s how that would work in the Southern Women data. First we compute the SimRank scores:
Then we peek inside the people similarity matrix:
EVELYN LAURA THERESA BRENDA CHARLOTTE FRANCES ELEANOR PEARL RUTH
EVELYN 1.000 0.267 0.262 0.266 0.259 0.275 0.248 0.255 0.237
LAURA 0.267 1.000 0.262 0.277 0.270 0.287 0.280 0.237 0.247
THERESA 0.262 0.262 1.000 0.262 0.273 0.270 0.264 0.254 0.256
BRENDA 0.266 0.277 0.262 1.000 0.290 0.287 0.279 0.235 0.246
CHARLOTTE 0.259 0.270 0.273 0.290 1.000 0.276 0.269 0.175 0.256
FRANCES 0.275 0.287 0.270 0.287 0.276 1.000 0.305 0.280 0.256
ELEANOR 0.248 0.280 0.264 0.279 0.269 0.305 1.000 0.279 0.294
PEARL 0.255 0.237 0.254 0.235 0.175 0.280 0.279 1.000 0.279
RUTH 0.237 0.247 0.256 0.246 0.256 0.256 0.294 0.279 1.000
VERNE 0.201 0.207 0.222 0.206 0.198 0.202 0.246 0.276 0.288
VERNE
EVELYN 0.201
LAURA 0.207
THERESA 0.222
BRENDA 0.206
CHARLOTTE 0.198
FRANCES 0.202
ELEANOR 0.246
PEARL 0.276
RUTH 0.288
VERNE 1.000
And the group similarity matrix:
6/27 3/2 4/12 9/26 2/25 5/19 3/15 9/16 4/8 6/10
6/27 1.000 0.343 0.314 0.312 0.287 0.277 0.224 0.226 0.178 0.137
3/2 0.343 1.000 0.312 0.311 0.285 0.276 0.224 0.228 0.200 0.141
4/12 0.314 0.312 1.000 0.314 0.288 0.265 0.226 0.220 0.179 0.138
9/26 0.312 0.311 0.314 1.000 0.287 0.256 0.230 0.214 0.186 0.137
2/25 0.287 0.285 0.288 0.287 1.000 0.260 0.235 0.226 0.187 0.146
5/19 0.277 0.276 0.265 0.256 0.260 1.000 0.224 0.226 0.200 0.171
3/15 0.224 0.224 0.226 0.230 0.235 0.224 1.000 0.221 0.204 0.209
9/16 0.226 0.228 0.220 0.214 0.226 0.226 0.221 1.000 0.221 0.214
4/8 0.178 0.200 0.179 0.186 0.187 0.200 0.204 0.221 1.000 0.234
6/10 0.137 0.141 0.138 0.137 0.146 0.171 0.209 0.214 0.234 1.000
Like before we can use these results to define two sets of distances:
Subject to hierarchical clustering:
And plot:
Get cluster memberships for people and groups from the hclust
object:
EVELYN LAURA THERESA BRENDA CHARLOTTE FRANCES ELEANOR PEARL
1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2
RUTH VERNE DOROTHY MYRNA KATHERINE SYLVIA NORA HELEN
2 2 2 3 3 3 3 3
OLIVIA FLORA
4 4
6/27 3/2 4/12 9/26 2/25 5/19 3/15 9/16 4/8 2/23 6/10 4/7 11/21
1 1 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 3 3 3
8/3
3
And block the bi-adjacency matrix:
p <- ggcorrplot(t(A[names(clus.p), names(clus.g)]),
colors = c("white", "white", "red"))
p <- p + theme(legend.position = "none",
axis.text.y = element_text(size = 8),
axis.text.x = element_text(size = 8, angle = 0),
)
p <- p + scale_x_discrete(position = "top")
p <- p + geom_hline(yintercept = 7.5, linewidth = 2, color = "blue")
p <- p + geom_hline(yintercept = 11.5, linewidth = 2, color = "blue")
p <- p + geom_hline(yintercept = 16.5, linewidth = 2, color = "blue")
p <- p + geom_vline(xintercept = 8.5, linewidth = 2, color = "blue")
p
Which produces a familiar block partition of persons and events.
Eigenvector Status
Measures of status and prestige are particularly applicable to two-mode networks. The reason is that the reflective principle behind these measures interacts nicely with the duality principle.
For instance, when it comes to eigenvector-style measures, the neat idea that people are central if they belong to central groups and groups and central if their members are central people (with people centrality defined by membership in central groups) can be effectively captured by these metrics (Bonacich 1991).
Thus if \(x\) are the status scores for people, and \(y\) are the status scores for groups, then the \(x\) scores should be given by the sum of the \(y\) scores of the groups each person belongs, and the \(y\) scores should be given by the sum of the \(x\) scores of their members.
In mathese:
\[ x = \mathbf{A}^Ty \]
\[ y = \mathbf{A}x \]
Once again, producing another instance of a cat chasing its own tail (we need to know the values of \(y\) to figure out the values of \(x\) and we need to know the values of \(x\) to figure out the values of \(y\)).
How do we proceed? Well, let’s bring back our trusty status distribution game:
status1 <- function(A) {
n <- nrow(A) #number of actors
x <- rep(1, n) #initial status vector set to all ones
w <- 1
k <- 0 #initializing counter
while (w > 0.0001) {
o.x <- x #old status scores
x <- A %*% x #new scores a function of old scores and adjacency matrix
x <- x/norm(x, type = "E") #normalizing new status scores
w <- abs(sum(abs(x) - abs(o.x))) #diff. between new and old scores
k <- k + 1 #incrementing while counter
}
return(as.vector(x))
}
Then the main question is over what matrix will the status game be played for both people and groups?
As Bonacich (1991) noted, the projection matrices of Breiger (1974) are natural candidates for this task. Let’s try it out.
For people this would be:
EVELYN LAURA THERESA BRENDA CHARLOTTE FRANCES ELEANOR PEARL
0.335 0.309 0.371 0.313 0.168 0.209 0.228 0.180
RUTH VERNE MYRNA KATHERINE SYLVIA NORA HELEN DOROTHY
0.236 0.218 0.187 0.220 0.277 0.264 0.201 0.131
OLIVIA FLORA
0.070 0.070
And for groups:
6/27 3/2 4/12 9/26 2/25 5/19 3/15 9/16 4/8 6/10 2/23 4/7 11/21
0.142 0.150 0.253 0.176 0.322 0.328 0.384 0.507 0.380 0.170 0.090 0.203 0.113
8/3
0.113
Lo and behold, these are the status scores we seek. It turns out they can be computed by figuring out the leading eigenvector (what our status game does for any matrix) of the Breiger projection matrices (Bonacich 1991):
\[ \lambda x = (\mathbf{A}\mathbf{A}^T)x \]
\[ \lambda y = (\mathbf{A}^T\mathbf{A})y \]
In R
we can do this using the eigen
function:
eig.p <- eigen(P)
eig.g <- eigen(G)
p.s <- eig.p$vector[, 1] * -1
g.s <- eig.g$vector[, 1] * -1
names(p.s) <- rownames(A)
names(g.s) <- colnames(A)
round(p.s, 3)
EVELYN LAURA THERESA BRENDA CHARLOTTE FRANCES ELEANOR PEARL
0.335 0.309 0.371 0.313 0.168 0.209 0.228 0.180
RUTH VERNE MYRNA KATHERINE SYLVIA NORA HELEN DOROTHY
0.236 0.218 0.187 0.220 0.277 0.264 0.201 0.131
OLIVIA FLORA
0.070 0.070
6/27 3/2 4/12 9/26 2/25 5/19 3/15 9/16 4/8 6/10 2/23 4/7 11/21
0.142 0.150 0.253 0.176 0.322 0.328 0.384 0.507 0.379 0.170 0.090 0.203 0.113
8/3
0.113
Neat! These are the same scores we obtained by playing our status game. The scores are also readily interpretable: The most central people belong to the most central (largest membership) groups and the most central groups are the ones that attract the most central (highest activity) members.
Another way of thinking of the eigenvector centrality of each node in this context is as a weighted sum1 of the eigenvector centralities on the nodes in the other mode they are connected to (Faust 1997, 170).
So for any person, let’s say \(EVELYN\), their eigenvector centrality is equal to:
Which is indeed Evelyn’s Eigenvector score.
The same goes for the eigenvector score of groups, which are just a weighted sum of the Eigenvector centralities of the people who belong to them:
Which is indeed the eigenvector score for the event held on 6/27. Duality at work!
Finally, here are the Southern Women dual Eigenvector Centralities in tabular form:
library(kableExtra)
p.dat <- data.frame(People = rownames(A), Eig.Cent = round(p.s, 3))
p.dat <- p.dat[order(p.dat$Eig.Cent, decreasing = TRUE), ]
kbl(p.dat, format = "html", , align = c("l", "c"), row.names = FALSE) %>%
column_spec(1, bold = TRUE) %>%
kable_styling(full_width = TRUE,
bootstrap_options = c("hover", "condensed", "responsive"))
People | Eig.Cent |
---|---|
THERESA | 0.371 |
EVELYN | 0.335 |
BRENDA | 0.313 |
LAURA | 0.309 |
SYLVIA | 0.277 |
NORA | 0.264 |
RUTH | 0.236 |
ELEANOR | 0.228 |
KATHERINE | 0.220 |
VERNE | 0.218 |
FRANCES | 0.209 |
HELEN | 0.201 |
MYRNA | 0.187 |
PEARL | 0.180 |
CHARLOTTE | 0.168 |
DOROTHY | 0.131 |
OLIVIA | 0.070 |
FLORA | 0.070 |
g.dat <- data.frame(Groups = colnames(A), Eig.Cent = round(g.s, 3))
g.dat <- g.dat[order(g.dat$Eig.Cent, decreasing = TRUE), ]
kbl(g.dat, format = "html", align = c("l", "c"), row.names = FALSE) %>%
column_spec(1, bold = TRUE) %>%
kable_styling(full_width = TRUE,
bootstrap_options = c("hover", "condensed", "responsive"))
Groups | Eig.Cent |
---|---|
9/16 | 0.507 |
3/15 | 0.384 |
4/8 | 0.379 |
5/19 | 0.328 |
2/25 | 0.322 |
4/12 | 0.253 |
4/7 | 0.203 |
9/26 | 0.176 |
6/10 | 0.170 |
3/2 | 0.150 |
6/27 | 0.142 |
11/21 | 0.113 |
8/3 | 0.113 |
2/23 | 0.090 |
Core and Periphery
As noted by Borgatti and Everett (2000), the Bonacich Eigenvector scores are also a model of a core-periphery partition in the two-mode network. This is already evident in the definition of the dual centralities: Popular actors (who participate in many events) make the events they participate in more central, and central events (that have many actors) become central when they attract the popular kids. The most central actors and most central events will thus form a clique in the network separating them from the rest.
This means the Eigenvector scores can be used to partition any two-mode network into a core (popular kids, popular events) and a periphery (less popular kids, less popular events). All we need to do to see the partition is to re-order the rows and columns of the affiliation matrix according to the value of the magnitude of the Eigenvector scores for people and events:
p <- ggcorrplot(t(A[order(p.s), order(g.s)]),
colors = c("white", "white", "red"))
p <- p + theme(legend.position = "none",
axis.text.y = element_text(size = 8),
axis.text.x = element_text(size = 8, angle = 0),
)
p <- p + scale_x_discrete(position = "top")
p <- p + geom_hline(yintercept = 10.5, linewidth = 2, color = "blue")
p <- p + geom_vline(xintercept = 8.5, linewidth = 2, color = "blue")
p
Here the upper-right block reveals the core actors and events in the network; namely, the events almost universally attended by the most active participants (Everett and Borgatti 2013, table 2).
References
Footnotes
Where the weight (for obscure technical reasons) is the inverse of the square root of the first eigenvalue obtained from the
eigen
analysis.↩︎